Shortly after John passed away, the leading academic association in our field, the American Real Estate and Urban Economics Association (AREUEA) decided to honor him by creating the John Quigley Medal. You can read more about John at the appreciation I posted on the occasion of his untimely death in 2015.
In January I received surprising and humbling news, at the San Diego ASSA meeting; AREUEA chose me for this year's John Quigley medal.
From the AREUEA website:
"The John M. Quigley Medal for Advancing Real Estate and Urban Economics is to be awarded to the individual who best represents the many ways in which John significantly advanced the academic fields that span his collective works. These fields include real estate, urban economics, public finance, regional science and others.
"The medal will recognize the many dimensions in which John contributed to these fields. Specifically, candidates for the John M. Quigley Medal may have produced a record of scholarship that opens up new avenues of inquiry, have a demonstrated record of mentorship of young scholars, have supported institutional advances within these fields, or have been particularly effective at dissemination of these fields to public and professional practices.
I'm humbled to receive this award, first, because of my regard for John; second, because it's the highest award to which I could ever aspire, and from peers; and third, because of the list of terrific scholars who've preceded me in receiving this award. Fourth, because it's not false modesty to mention that there are a number of outstanding scholars who are sure to join our list in due course.
Let me briefly introduce the other Quigley medal awardees, to date.
The first recipient of the Quigley Medal is somebody very familiar to regular readers of this blog.
The first recipient of the Quigley Medal is somebody very familiar to regular readers of this blog.
Chip Case, Innovator in the Measurement of House Prices, and Teacher Extraordinaire
Like his good friend John Q, Chip passed away too young, in 2016. Too soon, but not too soon to be awarded the first-ever Quigley medal, and deservedly so.
Even though I’m the brother of a funeral director and have posted memorials of a few other late colleagues, such as Art Goldberger and Austin Jaffe, I haven’t written about any other John Quigley medal winners. Not because they aren’t worthy – far from it. It’s because they are all, thankfully, still with us.
So, having already written about John and Chip, let me pen brief notes about the other four scholars who proceeded me. I’m proud to know each of them, great researchers who have taught me much over the years.
Jan Brueckner, Versatile Leader in Urban Economics
Jan Brueckner of UC Irvine's Department of Economics has written many seminal works in urban economics and related fields. He’s graced Irvine for a decade and a half, after two decades at the University of Illinois (Champaign-Urbana) as well as serving as a visiting scholar at dozens of other institutions over the years.
For the better part of two decades Jan helped shaped our field as the editor of our leading journal, the Journal of Urban Economics. Jan’s own research spans of both theory and empirics. I have long admired Jan's approach to theory as he clearly follows Einstein’s dictum: “everything should be as simple as possible. But not more so.” The breadth of topics Jan has researched is extraordinary. His research spans housing, commercial real estate, urban models, public finance, mortgage design, and transportation. In the latter field he's especially known for his work on airlines. It’s hard to pick favorites from someone who hit the century mark in publications over 50 papers ago, but let me mention a few.
I’m intensely interested in global urbanization patterns. Since its publication in 1970, John Harris and Michael Todaro’s paper “Migration, Unemployment and Development: A Two Sector Analysis,” and its progeny, have influenced academic research on migration and the growth of cities. Their findings of also influenced many government policymakers’ view of the urbanization process in countries undergoing migration from rural areas to cities.
The essence of the Harris-Todaro model, is that urban workers in such countries – “less developed in the jargon of 1970” – are bifurcated into to separate markets. One is a high wage formal sector in which wages are set artificially high by minimum-wage and other regulations and institutions. Most workers labor in the other market, an informal sector with a much lower productivity-determined wage. In the Harris-Todaro model, the possibility of obtaining a high wage in the formal sector job attracts migrants from the countryside. But there are more such migrants than such jobs in their model, because of the presumed large gap between formal and informal sector wages. So there is therefore “too much” migration to the city, a wage gap that is not bid away in equilibrium, and an increase in structural unemployment.
As my late friend Steve Mayo used to say, “it would be a good story if it were true.” Research by Ian Scott; Jeff Williamson; and Sangeepta Pratap and Erwan Quintin represent many studies that show the assumption of strongly segmented labor markets with large wage gaps don’t hold up to empirical verification.
Despite these results, Harris-Todaro remains a "zombie theory." Despite having been largely killed by number of empirical studies, it still walks the earth. Professor Brueckner and his co-author Hyun-A Kim drive a new stake into its heart, with their paper "Land Markets in the Harris‐Todaro Model: A New Factor Equilibrating Rural‐Urban Migration." As their paper's title suggests, they show that once you introduce a land market, even granting segmented labor markets, urban residents take steps to smooth their consumption between periods of employment and unemployment; any formal-informal wage differentials will be capitalized in land prices, throttling the excess migration to the city.
Professor Brueckner has also helped me in my teaching. I taught urban economics since 1990, mainly to business students; most of those were real estate majors. Perhaps 20 percent of my urban econ students, on average, came from outside the business school. The majority of these were from urban planning; others came from public affairs and geography. Economics students were very welcome, whether from the economics department or from agriculture and applied economics. These combined econ majors were often outstanding participants, but maybe 5 percent of my urban students over the long run.
Because I teach many more business students than economics students, I spend much less time on formal modeling than most teachers of the subject. Of course I expose my students to the basic models – supply and demand, the Alonso-Muth-Mills model, Tiebout equilibrium, regional models such as input-output analysis, and so on.
Why spend less time on models than I would if I were teaching in econ department? The majority my students will, for better for worse, never write down a formal model, algebraic or geometric, once they leave my class. But they will work with data, constantly. So I spend a lot more time than is normal in such a class on data analysis and applied statistics. I sneak in a little bit of econometrics and I make sure they understand some basic properties of time series, ideas about endogeneity, and so on. I even try to talk them into being informal Bayesians. But for econ students and anyone else desiring a bit more of the traditional approach, I tell them to straightaway get a copy of Jan’s admirable little book, Lectures on Urban Economics, and work through the mostly geometric models in that volume. For advanced students I go a little further and recommend a work through Yannis Ioannides' excellent book From Neighborhoods to Nations: The Economics of Social Interactions.
If space permitted, we could delve into many other topics Jan has investigated, including the economics of airlines and other transport-related topics. Other favorites, which I'll refer to in later posts, include his work with Alain Bertaud on the effects of development regulations ("floor space index" in Mumbai, or "floor area ratio" as it's known in the U.S.), and a terrific paper Jan wrote with Yves Zenou on how the canonical Alonso-Muth-Mills model (see below) can be fruitfully modified to incorporate location-specific amenities. Jan and Yves use the model to explain why amenities-rich central Paris looks so very different from the downtowns of many U.S. cities.
In addition to his contributions to urban and regional economics, Jan is also an accomplished photographer.
Don Haurin is Professor Emeritus of Economics at Ohio State University. (Excuse my mistake, THE Ohio State University. As a long-time Wisconsin prof, I sometimes forget myself. Joking aside, whether you are in the Big 10 or not so lucky, even Badgers acknowledge that Ohio State has also married top scholarship to a great football program).
For many years I was skeptical of the proposition that it made much difference to household welfare whether someone owned or rented their home, beyond certain subsidies homeowners received through the tax code, and built into U.S. financial policy (Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, FHA, etc. See Green and Malpezzi for a summary of these subsidies. The Tax Cut & Jobs Act 2017 has greatly reduced, though not completely eliminated, tax preferences for homeownership.)
The tail wags the dog I thought, since these subsidies are usually justified by the purported existence of other, more general social benefits to homeownership. See for example, arguments from the National Association of Realtors, or Freddie Mac. Note that these links are recent, but the interest in homeownership goes back many decades; see, for example a statement on the subject from Herbert Hoover.
So about 25 years ago my friend Richard Green, who then shared my skepticism of wide-ranging homeownership external benefits, teamed with Michelle White to investigate whether there was any support in the data for such benefits to homeownership. Of course, correlation is not causality, and homeowners are very different than renters. To begin with everyone knows that American homeowners on average have significantly higher incomes than renters; they are also more likely to be white, even after controlling for income differences. We could list a number of other demographic and financial differences that could make it hard to cleanly estimate the effects of homeownership per se on household outcomes and characteristics. Thus the first problem Green and White had to tackle was this possibility of a spurious correlation between social outcomes and homeownership.
To keep our discussion here brief, suffice it to say that Green and White examined several data sets and controlled for a number of other independent variables that could have driven social outcomes. Social outcomes could include, for example, how long children stayed in school, whether they later had contact with the criminal justice system, and so on. They also used econometric methods (described in more detail in their paper) to mitigate problems from real-world imperfect specifications. To their surprise they found that homeownership mattered even after controlling for as many other determinants as they could muster and adopting the best available methods for sample selection bias.
Green and White’s paper touched off a flurry of additional research on this topic. In a series of papers Don Haurin and co-authors have greatly extended and enriched this literature. A good example is Dietz and Haurin’s (2003) survey paper, in which they examine homeownership’s possible effects on:
• Household wealth and portfolio choice
• Household mobility
• Labor force participation
• Urban structure and segregation
• Home maintenance
• Political and social participation
• Health
• Demographic outcomes
• Self-esteem
• Child outcomes
Dietz and Haurin provide a critique of the many studies that lack sufficient control variables, both variables that affect the outcome of interest (e.g. child outcomes) and the key intervening variable of homeownership. In addition to garden-variety omitted variable bias, we may be confounding the effect of the homeownership rate with the missing variable, so that observed results may be spurious.
These and other econometric problems are reviewed in Dietz and Haurin. They also examine how choice of model and the type of data can mitigate these problems. Best practices are described.
Their critical review of data, and econometric methods, suggest pre-1990 findings can be suspect. More recent studies with better data and methods, like Green and White, attacked the endemic sample selection problem full on, although it’s only mitigated, never completely defeated. The evidence reviewed by Dietz and Haurin support the idea that the desire for eventual homeownership is an important motive for increased household savings. Other mooted effects on labor supply, fertility and consumption are “not proven.”
Homeownership lowers mobility, as is well established, but potential spillovers into labor markets are harder to find. Positive ceteris paribus effects of homeownership on child outcomes such as education and lack of contact with the criminal justice system have been repeatedly documented. Many knowledge gaps remain, including but not limited to analysis by type of structures, and differential impacts by race and ethnicity. Despite a number of research papers, evidence on the relationship between housing tenure and support for restrictive regulations and housing market – William Fischel’s famous Homevoter Hypothesis – is still somewhat fragmentary. Much remains to be done.
Other often cited, superficially plausible in the data, have not been carefully tested for example links between homeownership and political participation, urban form, or support for restrictive zoning. Solid studies find that homeownership affects a number of child outcomes such as school completion rates.
Prof. Haurin has studied a wide range of other topics on housing and urban issues. He and his co-authors, often former students, have undertaken studies of fluctuations in the rate of homeownership; how to construct improved real estate price indexes, and use them to study house price volatility. He’s undertaken some of the earliest research on Hispanic experiences in housing markets, as well as more technical work on the prediction of turning points in house prices. More recent research has focused on rigorous modeling of how sellers set list prices for houses, and how expectations are best modeled in the housing market.
Jim Kau, Who Changed the Way We Look at Mortgage Defaults
James Kau, C. Herman and Mary Virginia Terry Professor Emeritus of Business Administration at the University of Georgia, has made many contributions to urban economics; housing; but he's best known for his work in real estate finance, especially rigorous models of mortgage default and prepayment.
Professor Kau’s research interests are especially broad, spanning public finance and governance as well as real estate and finance. In my world he’s best known for his work on mortgage analytics.
A good place to start is his 1995 survey of “Option Theoretic Pricing of Mortgages,” with Donald Keenan. Mortgages of all kinds, like most loans, are subject to default and subsequent losses. The majority of U.S. residential mortgages are made at fixed rates, but are prepayable without significant penalty. Thus, when rents fall, rational borrowers prepay, and refinance at the new lower rate. Since the prior lender loses a formerly profitable cash flow stream and must now reinvest in a less favorable rate, this prepayment risk is of considerable interest, along with more common default risks. Furthermore, these twin risks are not necessarily independent. Falling rates presumably increase the probability of prepaying; the new lower rate after refinance may forestall some defaults, to give but one example.
Most U.S. mortgages are nonrecourse, which reduces but does not eliminate the cost of rational default, i.e. default when the value of the mortgages exceeds the value of the house.
It’s conventionally accepted, and perfectly logical, that falling rates can raise housing values and thus make defaults less likely. (See evidence here that it’s capital flows, more than rates, that drive prices; but there’s ample evidence that rates still matter.)
Suppose that rates are falling. In one model of default, based on a “razor’s edge” decision, the borrower computes the present value of 10 years of payments at the old and new rates; and as soon as the present value of the savings exceeds $500, they refinance. But if they refinance immediately, they give up the option to refinance later with still lower rates. Of course rates could rise instead of fall, which makes the modeling a little interesting.
Nevertheless, any time an agent takes a decision that commits them to a course of action for a period of time, an option is involved. Dixit and Pindyk is an excellent introduction to the structure of several kinds of options and how to price them.
Kau, Keenan and Munneke analyze mortgages as a type of option on an underlying asset, namely a house. Many analysts faced with options turn immediately to the workhorse Black-Scholes option pricing model for a simple stylized asset, specifically the short run call option on a security with a fixed return. Kau and colleagues point out that mortgage contracts are, of course, more complex.
Specifically, Kau et al. survey how to set up models that can be used to price several alternative mortgage designs. Mortgages can be characterized by fixed payments or adjustable rates with experiments or graduated payments. They do not limit themselves to housing markets. We have already noted that residential mortgages in the U.S. are generally nonrecourse with inexpensive prepayment. Commercial mortgages generally have recourse and pre-payment penalties and lockout provisions that require a different model. The black Scholes model is of little direct utility here. Kau et al. review and explain solution methods for applicable models, using both continuous and discrete time variants.
The Kau and Keenan paper is one of several places to begin the rigorous study of mortgages. See Green (2013) and Fabozzi (2016) for example. As Kau and Keenan note there many extensions possible and sometimes required, for example how the state variables of interest rates and house prices are modeled, and introducing explicit transaction costs into the models. And of course of mortgages are derivative securities written on real estate assets the events of the 2000’s remind us that we began to commonly write derivatives on derivatives – and sometimes derivatives on the second derivatives – which could get us into some wicked hard problems when trying to evaluate and price these instruments. Kau and Kennan provide a good entry point to those problems.
Unconditionally, minorities have higher rates of default and foreclosures (see e.g. Gerardi and Willen, Subprime Mortgages Foreclosures and Urban Neighborhoods). By itself this factoid tells us little. Minorities (most studies have focused on black-white differences) tend to have lower and more volatile incomes, (Ziliak, Hardy and Bollinger), lower credit scores, and perhaps a dozen other systematic differences that confound the relationship between race and mortgage default.
One understudied effect comes from racial differences in prepayment behavior. Black borrowers are less likely to prepay when rates decline, as Kau et al. document. Ceteris paribus, such behavior should make black borrowers more attractive to lenders. There are several ways lenders might treat attractive (or unattractive) borrowers differently. The first of course is whether they lend at all. A second is whether loans are offered on the same terms – including but not limited to loan-to-value ratios, and of course interest rates. The latter is the focus of Kau et al.
Using the framework developed by Deng, Quigley and Van Order, Professor Kau and colleagues found that once they controlled for prepayment, as well as loan-to-value and other contract terms, borrowers in predominantly black neighborhoods significantly were offered higher contract rates than the full model predicts for color-blind competitive markets.
Professor Kau’s study is of course not the last word. Among other issues, as laid out clearly in the review paper by Anthony Yezer, a clear understanding and clean estimates of true mortgage discrimination require studying the entire process, from application through mortgage termination. Data requirements are hard to meet, and such studies have not yet been done.
Many questions remain. Kau et al. did not have credit score data, to point out one shortcoming; and neighborhood variables are useful but imperfect proxies for household circumstances. Taking the results at face value, competing hypotheses remain for why such differentials might exist, as Kau et al. note. Is it straight racism? Unconscious bias? Ignorance of the true model of prepayment and default? The authors suggest another logical possibility, a potentially perverse explanation that in making loans truly race-blind lenders could be failing to credit minority borrowers with the benefits of their lower propensities to prepay. Whenever the underlying cause, Professor Kau and his colleagues provide an interesting twist on the standard stories of and debates about racial discrimination in mortgage behavior.
Ed Mills, One of the Founders of Modern Urban Economics
Edwin Mills is Professor Emeritus of Real Estate at Northwestern. Before his tenure at Northwestern, he was a long-time Professor of Economics at Princeton. Mills is the author of some 20 books and 130 papers. For many years he was the sole editor of the Journal of Urban Economics, the leading journal of our field; and he has served as co-editor and editorial board member of many other journals.
My simple introduction to him in class: the father of urban economics. I think the other Medal recipients would point to Professor Mills' deep influence on all of us. Even John Quigley would give Ed pride of place, along with John's own mentor, the late John Kain; William Alonso; and Richard Muth. We often refer to the canonical model of land use within a monocentric city as the "Alonso-Muth-Mills model" or simply "AMM."
Ed was the third recipient of the Quigley medal. His career is so distinguished that we are not dissing Chip or Jan in the least if we ask, “what took us so long?” (In fairness, there are a couple people coming after me who might ask the same question.) One measure of the esteem in which Ed is held is that for two decades AREUEA has awarded the Edwin Mills Best Paper Award for the top research presented at our annual meeting.
My first textbook, as a student, and again as a teacher, was Edwin Mills and Bruce Hamilton’s Urban Economics. (Bruce Hamilton, one of a legion of outstanding Mills PhD students over the years, served as co-author in later editions.) Now out of print, Mills and Hamilton has been largely superseded by Jan Brueckner’s fine introduction to the theory (see above), Arthur O’Sullivan’s wide-ranging undergraduate textbook, John McDonald and Dan McMillen’s excellent foray tying urban economics and real estate together, and a classic if somewhat older text on real estate and urban from Denise DiPasquale and Bill Wheaton. (Denise and Bill are currently updating their fine text, so watch that space). While each of these fine textbooks has extended Mills’s original textbook, I think these authors will all acknowledge a debt to Ed Mills and his co-author Hamilton. With 1600 citations in Google scholar, it’s long been viewed as a standard.
I eventually migrated from Mills and Hamilton to other texts, but I long continued assigning his beautiful review of the field published by the Brookings Institution.
Along with Alonso’s Location and Land Use, and Muth’s Cities and Housing, Edwin Mills’ Studies in the Structure of the Urban Economy was one of the foundational works in urban economics, and along with some classic “second generation” works like Kain and Quigley’s Housing Markets and Racial Discrimination formed the basis of my own early education in the field.
A follow-on paper by Mills and Tan on population density set the stage for my own work on international comparisons with Alain Bertaud. Mills and Tan relate flattening population density gradients to rising incomes and growing cities. Again Mills used simple data, the best available, and they were careful to make mainly qualitative comparisons. In our study, thanks to Alain’s careful work over several decades, we have the advantage of comparable data collected and analyzed for over 50 large metropolitan areas around the world.
My colleague and good friend Kyung-Hwan Kim was one of dozens of Mills PhD students; as I’ve remarked elsewhere, Mills work with Kim and other co-authors was instrumental in opening my eyes to the economies of Seoul and other fascinating Korean cities.
Ed is one of several scholars whose interest in land use and development regulation inspired my own -- Bill Fischel and Lou Rose also come to mind, among others, and of course I built some of my domestic U.S. work on data collection by Peter Linneman and Anita Summers. My international work in this area was inspired by Alain Bertaud and Ramgopal Agarwala, among others.
I was especially taken with Mills’ simple but elegant analysis of urban population density gradients in Studies in the Structure. The monograph applied simple but clever techniques to the limited set of historical data then available. Mills’ results provided a number of insights that were later confirmed as we developed more detailed small area data and better technology for analysis (geographical information systems, advances in spatial econometrics).
One of my first papers with Jim Follain tested some of Mills’s predictions. I often paired Follain and Malpezzi with a related paper by Mills and Price to teach students how simple, not terribly realistic urban models could nevertheless tell us a lot about urban decentralization (later referred to as “sprawl”). By comparing the two papers I could also explain to students how some results (for example the effects of income on decentralization) could be robust to different studies and methods; while others (is race or poverty a stronger driver of decentralization?) are more fragile than we’d like. Our classroom review highlighted how you can learn a lot from empirical work; but how you should also never put too much stock in any single study, whatever its care and/or prominence.
This paper jogs my memory of an early formative experience. Follain and I had recently published our paper on tests of the standard urban model of Mills and others, when I then moved from the Urban Institute to the World Bank. In grad school at the same time, I’d recently shifted from international affairs to economics. I hadn’t yet taken my field exams, much less finished my Ph.D. Doug Keare, my new division chief, invited me, as the literal new kid on the block, to present my paper with Follain in a lunchtime seminar. Okay.
Entering the room, I found my new friend and colleague Steve Mayo, and a number of accomplished World Bank urban economists including Keare, Kyu Sik Lee, Andy Hamer, Greg Ingram and others. Also in the room were several visiting scholars: Vern Henderson, Jeff Williamson, Charlie Becker, and Ed Mills. I gulped because that’s quite a lineup and I was still a lowly graduate student. I felt pretty overmatched.
Nevertheless, I proceeded to present my paper, arguing at one point Greg Ingram’s sophisticated simulation models with John Kain and others hadn’t fully superseded the simpler monocentric model. Before long I was explaining how, in our view, the Mills model nevertheless needed to incorporate a number of variables that could be described as – gasp – sociological.
I awaited my shredding. It never exactly came. I think Ed and the rest must’ve recently all read Portia’s famous speech about “the quality of mercy.”
They gave mercy and I took it, with gratitude. There was a spirited discussion, and plenty of healthy criticism of my work. But I learned the value of, in today’s jargon, disagreeing without being disagreeable. There was never a hint of anyone’s rank or reputation, just the quality of data and method an argument, and a collegial search for truth, or as close to truth is we could come. I was presenting, and they did me the honor of treating me as an equal for the duration, though I was anything but.
Over the years, Ed Mills, and the others in that room, and several others taught me a shortcut to evaluating someone’s character. How do they treat those below them in the food chain? With respect, evaluating their ideas and work on the merits, without condescension? How do they treat those nominally above them? Evenhandedly, again appropriately respectful, but exhibiting the integrity and sense of self and yes occasional courage to offer their honest criticisms, without regard to their own popularity or consequence? This integrity is something I saw early and deeply in Ed Mills, in John Quigley for whom this medal is named, and I’m pleased to say in each of my preceding award winners.
Nobody Gets a John Quigley Model Without a Lot of Help
The secrets of my success? As Hall of Fame pitcher Lefty Gomez would put it, "Is it better to be lucky or to be good?" My usual answer is "yes," though along with Robert H. Frank and Benjamin Franklin, I put a lot of weight on luck. I come from a family that spent the last century or so moving from tenant farmers in Italy, to coal miners in Western Pennsylvania, to small scale (and small profits) tile and terrazzo installation. Like Warren Buffett, I "won the ovarian lottery;" it's still an advantage, ex ante, but in 1952 to be born a white male in the United States was a huge leg up. I was one of about 1.7 million 1952 claimants of that particular prize in the lottery, out of about 98 million global births; roughly 1 out of 60. And with the help of family, good teachers, and some more luck, I was well educated. To my knowledge I am the second in my family to finish a BA, and the first graduate degree, although many others have followed.
I've continued the string of good luck, especially when it comes to colleagues and co-authors. If I've had one talent over the years, it's been to find great people to work with.
Here's a photo of me with GWU Economics Professor Tony Yezer, who was my PhD advisor. Tony was and is a great teacher, and has been a great supporter in many other ways over the years.
From the Urban Institute to the World Bank to the University of Wisconsin, I've had at least 40 coauthors and hundreds of other supportive colleagues, from whom I've learned a lot. And that doesn't even begin to count literally hundreds of others I could name over the past 40 years, AREUEA members and many others, from dozens of countries. Obviously I can't do justice to all those colleagues and friends here, but in addition to Tony, I have to mention a few by name here.
Of many colleagues at the Urban Institute -- Ray Struyk, who got me started, Larry Ozanne and Tom Thibodeau, a dozen more come to mind -- I have to give my friend Jim Follain credit for giving me the opportunity to move from working as an assistant to becoming a full partner in research and to generously sharing credit for our joint work.
At the World Bank, I learned so much from colleagues like Bertrand Renaud, Jim Wright, Bob Buckley, Larry Hannah, and of course Alain Bertaud; again far too many to name. And the Bank gave me to learn from dozens of colleagues, Vinod Tewari, Duncan Maclennan, Marja Hoek-Smit, Solly Angel, Kyung-Hwan Kim are the tip of that iceberg. But one person stands out among that large list, my late friend and colleague Steve Mayo. When the late Doug Keare and others organized a research project on "Housing Demand and Finance in Developing Countries," they hired Steve to direct the project, and me as the directee. But again, like Jim Follain, Steve was quick to share responsibilities and credit, and to mentor me through a critical stage in my career.
Plus, it was through Steve that I came to know John Quigley as a friend as well as a remarkable source of insight and knowledge.
My 26 years at Wisconsin were a wonderful opportunity, with many colleagues both within the Graaskamp Center as well as elsewhere in the Wisconsin School of Business and throughout the University. I could quickly name a hundred. Wisconsin was also a point of entry for a wide range of real estate and urban development professionals, some of them UW alums, some Graaskamp Center Board members, far too many to name here. And don't forget the 3,000 students I taught there over the years. More than a few of those students taught me back, to be sure.
But of all those marvelous Wisconsin connections I'd have to give pride of place to my friend, colleague and co-author Richard Green. Richard joined up in 1990, the same year as Jim Shilling and myself. Richard had recently completed his Ph.D. in economics, writing on international trade under famed UW Professor Robert Baldwin. While Richard's wife, Patricia Harris, completed her medical education at UW, Richard took a temporary job as the Chief Economist of the Wisconsin Realtors Association. I might go even further, but no one could question that no other state real estate trade group has ever had such an accomplished economist grace their staff. Together Richard and I wrote half a dozen papers and our Primer on U.S. Housing Markets and Housing Policy; we could have, should have, written a dozen more. (Though we're not done, yet.)
I blog, but I don't do Facebook or other places where you'll find photo galleries. So here are a few photos of colleagues whom I've learned from and collaborated with over the years; these are primarily friends I've also coauthored with at one time or another. If you want to see more, I've been collecting more photos within the presentation I gave a few years ago when I retired from Wisconsin, click here for the current version. If you're a glutton for punishment, and want to read more of those papers, you can find a (slightly dated) CV here, and my entries at Google Scholar here. But of course now that I'm blogging, well, check out my other blog entries here.
I'm Not Quite Done Yet...
As an Emeritus Professor, I remain connected to the Graaskamp Center and to the University of Wisconsin more generally. I've long been connected to the Homer Hoyt Institute, and for the last several years I've been honored to serve as the Dean of the Hoyt Group's Weimer School Academic Fellows. Morris Davis, formerly a colleague at UW, and now Paul V. Profeta Professor of Real Estate at Rutgers, has recruited me to help out with their Center from time to time.
And it's great to live in the Boston area. We moved here in 2014 after retirement for the temperate climate. On arrival, we found one of our grandsons lived here, what a coincidence! With his parents, too, that's OK. Another great coincidence is that it turns out there are several universities in the area, and many friends at MIT, Harvard, Boston College, Tufts, and the Boston Fed have been very welcoming and generous with their time. And of course I remain an active member of AREUEA.
I'm working on several projects at the moment, some with long-time coauthors (see above), some with some new ones. Yongping Liang and I are undertaking some new research on the metro-level analysis of housing supply and pricing. Jaime Luque, Antonio Mello, Stani Milcheva and I are writing a monograph on housing affordability, building on work we did for Stani's conference on the topic at UCL two years ago. Kyung-Hwan Kim and Peter Englund and I are revising a long-dormant paper on tenure choice across countries. Jay Sa-Aadu and I are revisiting urban policies in Africa, with our colleague Moussa Diop. And someday Richard Green and I will finally finish the second edition of the Housing Primer, with some help from Paul Carrillo.
Final Thoughts
The Quigley Medal is a very special honor both because it's from an Association I've learned much from and made many friends in; but also because it is named for John. You might have seen what I wrote about him several years ago, here.
As a further honor I'll be asked to deliver an address to AREUEA when we meet online again in DC at the end of May. (Yikes! That's next week!) Another blog post, coming soon, will tell you more about that address and provide some links for interested readers.
UPDATE: You can now find that presentation -- in PowerPoint, pdf, and a YouTube video -- here.
In the meantime, you can find out more about the Virtual National AREUEA Conference here. If you register by the end of May 27, you'll receive an email with instructions on how to sign into the conference along with links to papers and slides.
The AREUEA webpage notes that the conference is free to AREUEA members, but as I understand it, the conference is actually free to anyone who registers.
Here's the Conference Schedule:
I hope to "see" you at the conference on Thursday!
UPDATE: You can now find that presentation -- in PowerPoint, pdf, and a YouTube video -- here.
In the meantime, you can find out more about the Virtual National AREUEA Conference here. If you register by the end of May 27, you'll receive an email with instructions on how to sign into the conference along with links to papers and slides.
The AREUEA webpage notes that the conference is free to AREUEA members, but as I understand it, the conference is actually free to anyone who registers.
Here's the Conference Schedule:
May 28
11:30-11:35 | Welcome and Logistics |
11:35-1:15 | Commercial Real Estate (4-Paper Session) |
1:30-2:15 | Quigley Medal Lecture (Steve Malpezzi) |
2:35-4:15 | Urban Economics (4-Paper Session) |
4:30-5:15 | WREN Panel "Demystifying the Journal Publication Process" |
5:15-6:00 | WREN Networking Event |
May 29
10:00-11:40 | Household Finance (4-Paper Session) |
12:00-1:40 | Housing (4-Paper Session) |
1:40-3:00 | Industry Panel on Housing and Mortgage Markets |
I hope to "see" you at the conference on Thursday!
References
Agarwala, Ramgopal. Price Distortions and Growth in Developing Countries. World Bank Washington, DC, 1983.
Alonso, William. Location and Land Use: Toward a General Theory of Land Rent. Harvard University Press, 1964.
Bertaud, Alain. Order without Design. MIT Press, 2018.
Bertaud, Alain, and Jan K Brueckner. "Analyzing Building-Height Restrictions: Predicted Impacts and Welfare Costs." Regional Science and Urban Economics 35, no. 2 (2005): 109-25.
Bertaud, Alain, and Stephen Malpezzi. "The Spatial Distribution of Population in 52 World Cities." Madison, WI: James A. Graaskamp Center for Real Estate, 2013.
Brueckner, Jan K. "Lectures on Urban Economics." MIT Press Books 1 (2011).
Brueckner, Jan K. "Slums in Developing Countries: New Evidence for Indonesia." Journal of Housing Economics 22, no. 4 (December 2013 2013): 278-90.
Brueckner, Jan K., and Hyun-A Kim. "Land Markets in the Harris-Todaro Model: A New Factor Equilibrating Rural-Urban Migration." Journal of Regional Science 41, no. 3 (2001): 507-20.
Brueckner, Jan K., J.F. Thisse, and Yves Zenou. "Why Is Central Paris Rich and Downtown Detroit Poor?: An Amenity-Based Theory." European Economic Review 43, no. 1 (1999): 91-107.
Croce, Roberto M., and Donald R. Haurin. "Predicting Turning Points in the Housing Market." Journal of Housing Economics 18, no. 4 (2009): 281-93.
Davis, Morris A., Stephen Malpezzi and François Ortalo-Magné. "The Wisconsin Foreclosure and Unemployment Relief Plan (Wi-Fur)." James A. Graaskamp Center for Real Estate, http://www.bus.wisc.edu/realestate/wi-fur/.
Deng, Yongheng, John M Quigley, and Robert Van Order. "Mortgage Terminations, Heterogeneity and the Exercise of Mortgage Options." Econometrica 68 (2000): 275-308.
DiPasquale, Denise, and William C. Wheaton. Urban Economics and Real Estate Markets. Prentice Hall Englewood Cliffs, NJ, 1995.
Dixit, Avinash K, and Robert S Pindyck. Investment under Uncertainty. Princeton university press, 1994.
Fabozzi, Frank J, ed. The Handbook of Mortgage-Backed Securities. Seventh Edition ed: Oxford University Press, 2016.
Fischel, William. The Homevoter Hypothesis: How Home Values Influence Local Government Taxation, School Finance, and Land-Use Policies. Harvard University Press, 2001.
Fischel, William A. "Do Growth Controls Matter?". Lincoln Institute of Land Policy, Cambridge Massachusetts (1990).
Follain, James R., Jr., and Stephen Malpezzi. "The Flight to the Suburbs: Insights Gained from an Analysis of Central-City Vs Suburban Housing Costs." Journal of Urban Economics 9, no. 3 (May 1981): 381-98.
Frank, Robert H. Success and Luck: Good Fortune and the Myth of Meritocracy. Princeton University Press, 2016.
Franklin, Benjamin. The Autobiography of Benjamin Franklin. PF Collier, 1817.
Gatzlaff, Dean H, and Donald R Haurin. "Sample Selection and Biases in Local House Value Indices." Journal of Urban Economics 43, no. 2 (1998): 199-222.
Gerardi, Kristopher, and Paul Willen. "Subprime Mortgages, Foreclosures, and Urban Neighborhoods." The B. E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy 9, no. 3 (2009): 2232.
Green, Richard K. Introduction to Mortgages & Mortgage Backed Securities. Academic Press, 2013.
Green, Richard K., and Stephen Malpezzi. A Primer on U.S. Housing Markets and Housing Policy. American Real Estate and Urban Economics Association Monograph Series. Washington, D.C.: Urban Institute Press, 2003.
Grinstein-Weiss, Michal, Clinton Key, Shenyang Guo, Yeong Hun Yeo, and Krista Holub. "Homeownership and Wealth among Low-and Moderate-Income Households." Housing Policy Debate 23, no. 2 (2013): 259-79.
Hannah, Larry, Alain Bertaud, Stephen Malpezzi, and Stephen K Mayo. "Malaysia: The Housing Sector; Getting the Incentives Right." World Bank Sector Report 7292 (1989).
Hannah, Larry, Kyung Hwan Kim, and Edwin S Mills. "Land Use Controls and Housing Prices in Korea." Urban Studies 30, no. 1 (1993): 147-56.
Harris, John R, and Michael P Todaro. "Migration, Unemployment and Development: A Two-Sector Analysis." The American economic review 60, no. 1 (1970): 126-42.
Haurin, Donald R., Toby L. Parcel, and R. Jean Haurin. "Does Homeownership Affect Child Outcomes?" Real Estate Economics 30, no. 4 (2002): 635-66.
Ingram, Gregory K, John F Kain, and J Royce Ginn. "The Detroit Prototype of the NBER Urban Simulation Model." NBER Books (1972).
Ioannides, Yannis Menelaos. From Neighborhoods to Nations: The Economics of Social Interactions. Princeton University Press, 2013.
Kain, John F, and John M Quigley. Housing Markets and Racial Discrimination: A Microeconomic Analysis. National Bureau of Economic Research, 1975.
Kau, James B, Donald C Keenan, and Henry J Munneke. "Racial Discrimination and Mortgage Lending." The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 45, no. 2 (2012): 289-304.
Kau, James B, and Cheng F Lee. "Capital-Land Substitution and Urban Land Use." Journal of Regional Science 16, no. 1 (1976): 83-92.
Kim, Kyung-Hwan, and Edwin S Mills. "Korean Development and Urbanization: Prospects and Problems." World Development 16, no. 1 (1988): 157-67.
McDonald, John F, and Daniel P McMillen. Urban Economics and Real Estate: Theory and Policy. Wiley. com, 2010.
Mills, Edwin S. "Is Land Taxation Practical." Illinois Real Estate Letter 12, no. 4 (1998): 1-5.
———. Studies in the Structure of the Urban Economy. Johns Hopkins, 1972.
———. "A Thematic History of Urban Economic Analysis [with Comments by Dennis Epple and Wallace Oates]." Brookings-Wharton Papers on Urban Affairs (2000): 1-52.
———. "Welfare Aspects of National Policy toward City Sizes." Urban Studies 9, no. 1 (1972): 117.
———. "Why Do We Have Urban Density Controls?". Real Estate Economics 33, no. 3 (2005): 571-86.
Mills, Edwin S, and David M de Ferranti. "Market Choices and Optimum City Size." American Economic Review 61, no. 2 (1971): 340-45.
Mills, Edwin S, and Bruce W Hamilton. Urban Economics. Addison Wesley, 1994.
Mills, Edwin S, and Richard Price. "Metropolitan Suburbanization and Central City Problems." Journal of Urban Economics 15, no. 1 (1984): 1-17.
Mills, Edwin S, and Jee-Peng Tan. "A Comparison of Urban Population Density Functions in Developed and Developing Countries." Urban Studies 17, no. 3 (1980): 313-21.
Muth, Richard F. Cities and Housing: The Spatial Pattern of Urban Residential Land Use. University of Chicago Press, 1969.
O'Sullivan, Arthur. Urban Economics. McGraw Hill, 2009.
Pratap, Sangeeta, and Erwan Quintin. "Are Labor Markets Segmented in Developing Countries? A Semiparametric Approach." European Economic Review 50, no. 7 (2006): 1817-41.
Rose, Louis A. "Urban Land Supply: Natural and Contrived Restrictions." Journal of Urban Economics 25, no. 3 (1989): 325-45.
Scott, Ian. "Urban and Spatial Development in Mexico." (1982).
Williamson, Jeffrey G. "Migration and Urbanization." Handbook of development economics 1 (1988): 425-65.
Yezer, Anthony M.J. "A Review of Statistical Problems in the Measurement of Mortgage Market Discrimination and Credit Risk." Research Institute for Housing America and the Mortgage Bankers Association, 2010.
Yun, Lawrence, and Nadia Evangelou. "Social Benefits of Homeownership and Stable Housing." National Association of Realtors, 2016.
Zhang, Jing, Robert de Jong, and Donald Haurin. "Are Us Real House Prices Stationary? New Evidence from Univariate and Panel Data." Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics & Econometrics 20, no. 1 (2016): 1-18.
Ziliak, James P, Bradley Hardy, and Christopher Bollinger. "Earnings Volatility in America: Evidence from Matched Cps." Labour Economics 18, no. 6 (2011): 742-54.
Alonso, William. Location and Land Use: Toward a General Theory of Land Rent. Harvard University Press, 1964.
Bertaud, Alain. Order without Design. MIT Press, 2018.
Bertaud, Alain, and Jan K Brueckner. "Analyzing Building-Height Restrictions: Predicted Impacts and Welfare Costs." Regional Science and Urban Economics 35, no. 2 (2005): 109-25.
Bertaud, Alain, and Stephen Malpezzi. "The Spatial Distribution of Population in 52 World Cities." Madison, WI: James A. Graaskamp Center for Real Estate, 2013.
Brueckner, Jan K. "Lectures on Urban Economics." MIT Press Books 1 (2011).
Brueckner, Jan K. "Slums in Developing Countries: New Evidence for Indonesia." Journal of Housing Economics 22, no. 4 (December 2013 2013): 278-90.
Brueckner, Jan K., and Hyun-A Kim. "Land Markets in the Harris-Todaro Model: A New Factor Equilibrating Rural-Urban Migration." Journal of Regional Science 41, no. 3 (2001): 507-20.
Brueckner, Jan K., J.F. Thisse, and Yves Zenou. "Why Is Central Paris Rich and Downtown Detroit Poor?: An Amenity-Based Theory." European Economic Review 43, no. 1 (1999): 91-107.
Croce, Roberto M., and Donald R. Haurin. "Predicting Turning Points in the Housing Market." Journal of Housing Economics 18, no. 4 (2009): 281-93.
Davis, Morris A., Stephen Malpezzi and François Ortalo-Magné. "The Wisconsin Foreclosure and Unemployment Relief Plan (Wi-Fur)." James A. Graaskamp Center for Real Estate, http://www.bus.wisc.edu/realestate/wi-fur/.
Deng, Yongheng, John M Quigley, and Robert Van Order. "Mortgage Terminations, Heterogeneity and the Exercise of Mortgage Options." Econometrica 68 (2000): 275-308.
DiPasquale, Denise, and William C. Wheaton. Urban Economics and Real Estate Markets. Prentice Hall Englewood Cliffs, NJ, 1995.
Dixit, Avinash K, and Robert S Pindyck. Investment under Uncertainty. Princeton university press, 1994.
Fabozzi, Frank J, ed. The Handbook of Mortgage-Backed Securities. Seventh Edition ed: Oxford University Press, 2016.
Fischel, William. The Homevoter Hypothesis: How Home Values Influence Local Government Taxation, School Finance, and Land-Use Policies. Harvard University Press, 2001.
Fischel, William A. "Do Growth Controls Matter?". Lincoln Institute of Land Policy, Cambridge Massachusetts (1990).
Follain, James R., Jr., and Stephen Malpezzi. "The Flight to the Suburbs: Insights Gained from an Analysis of Central-City Vs Suburban Housing Costs." Journal of Urban Economics 9, no. 3 (May 1981): 381-98.
Frank, Robert H. Success and Luck: Good Fortune and the Myth of Meritocracy. Princeton University Press, 2016.
Franklin, Benjamin. The Autobiography of Benjamin Franklin. PF Collier, 1817.
Gatzlaff, Dean H, and Donald R Haurin. "Sample Selection and Biases in Local House Value Indices." Journal of Urban Economics 43, no. 2 (1998): 199-222.
Gerardi, Kristopher, and Paul Willen. "Subprime Mortgages, Foreclosures, and Urban Neighborhoods." The B. E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy 9, no. 3 (2009): 2232.
Green, Richard K. Introduction to Mortgages & Mortgage Backed Securities. Academic Press, 2013.
Green, Richard K., and Stephen Malpezzi. A Primer on U.S. Housing Markets and Housing Policy. American Real Estate and Urban Economics Association Monograph Series. Washington, D.C.: Urban Institute Press, 2003.
Grinstein-Weiss, Michal, Clinton Key, Shenyang Guo, Yeong Hun Yeo, and Krista Holub. "Homeownership and Wealth among Low-and Moderate-Income Households." Housing Policy Debate 23, no. 2 (2013): 259-79.
Hannah, Larry, Alain Bertaud, Stephen Malpezzi, and Stephen K Mayo. "Malaysia: The Housing Sector; Getting the Incentives Right." World Bank Sector Report 7292 (1989).
Hannah, Larry, Kyung Hwan Kim, and Edwin S Mills. "Land Use Controls and Housing Prices in Korea." Urban Studies 30, no. 1 (1993): 147-56.
Harris, John R, and Michael P Todaro. "Migration, Unemployment and Development: A Two-Sector Analysis." The American economic review 60, no. 1 (1970): 126-42.
Haurin, Donald R., Toby L. Parcel, and R. Jean Haurin. "Does Homeownership Affect Child Outcomes?" Real Estate Economics 30, no. 4 (2002): 635-66.
Ingram, Gregory K, John F Kain, and J Royce Ginn. "The Detroit Prototype of the NBER Urban Simulation Model." NBER Books (1972).
Ioannides, Yannis Menelaos. From Neighborhoods to Nations: The Economics of Social Interactions. Princeton University Press, 2013.
Kain, John F, and John M Quigley. Housing Markets and Racial Discrimination: A Microeconomic Analysis. National Bureau of Economic Research, 1975.
Kau, James B, Donald C Keenan, and Henry J Munneke. "Racial Discrimination and Mortgage Lending." The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 45, no. 2 (2012): 289-304.
Kau, James B, and Cheng F Lee. "Capital-Land Substitution and Urban Land Use." Journal of Regional Science 16, no. 1 (1976): 83-92.
Kim, Kyung-Hwan, and Edwin S Mills. "Korean Development and Urbanization: Prospects and Problems." World Development 16, no. 1 (1988): 157-67.
McDonald, John F, and Daniel P McMillen. Urban Economics and Real Estate: Theory and Policy. Wiley. com, 2010.
Mills, Edwin S. "Is Land Taxation Practical." Illinois Real Estate Letter 12, no. 4 (1998): 1-5.
———. Studies in the Structure of the Urban Economy. Johns Hopkins, 1972.
———. "A Thematic History of Urban Economic Analysis [with Comments by Dennis Epple and Wallace Oates]." Brookings-Wharton Papers on Urban Affairs (2000): 1-52.
———. "Welfare Aspects of National Policy toward City Sizes." Urban Studies 9, no. 1 (1972): 117.
———. "Why Do We Have Urban Density Controls?". Real Estate Economics 33, no. 3 (2005): 571-86.
Mills, Edwin S, and David M de Ferranti. "Market Choices and Optimum City Size." American Economic Review 61, no. 2 (1971): 340-45.
Mills, Edwin S, and Bruce W Hamilton. Urban Economics. Addison Wesley, 1994.
Mills, Edwin S, and Richard Price. "Metropolitan Suburbanization and Central City Problems." Journal of Urban Economics 15, no. 1 (1984): 1-17.
Mills, Edwin S, and Jee-Peng Tan. "A Comparison of Urban Population Density Functions in Developed and Developing Countries." Urban Studies 17, no. 3 (1980): 313-21.
Muth, Richard F. Cities and Housing: The Spatial Pattern of Urban Residential Land Use. University of Chicago Press, 1969.
O'Sullivan, Arthur. Urban Economics. McGraw Hill, 2009.
Pratap, Sangeeta, and Erwan Quintin. "Are Labor Markets Segmented in Developing Countries? A Semiparametric Approach." European Economic Review 50, no. 7 (2006): 1817-41.
Rose, Louis A. "Urban Land Supply: Natural and Contrived Restrictions." Journal of Urban Economics 25, no. 3 (1989): 325-45.
Scott, Ian. "Urban and Spatial Development in Mexico." (1982).
Williamson, Jeffrey G. "Migration and Urbanization." Handbook of development economics 1 (1988): 425-65.
Yezer, Anthony M.J. "A Review of Statistical Problems in the Measurement of Mortgage Market Discrimination and Credit Risk." Research Institute for Housing America and the Mortgage Bankers Association, 2010.
Yun, Lawrence, and Nadia Evangelou. "Social Benefits of Homeownership and Stable Housing." National Association of Realtors, 2016.
Zhang, Jing, Robert de Jong, and Donald Haurin. "Are Us Real House Prices Stationary? New Evidence from Univariate and Panel Data." Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics & Econometrics 20, no. 1 (2016): 1-18.
Ziliak, James P, Bradley Hardy, and Christopher Bollinger. "Earnings Volatility in America: Evidence from Matched Cps." Labour Economics 18, no. 6 (2011): 742-54.
Jaideep Puri Realtor
ReplyDeleteJaideep Puri Realtor
Jaideep Puri Realtor
Jaideep Puri Realtor
Lottery is something majority of the people in the world want to win, not only winning the lottery, but they want to win big, i have been playing the lottery for couple of years now, but i haven,t really win big, personally i always think there is something behind all those winners who always win big, because my intense always tell me that every thing is possible, i manage to get in contact with one of the biggest lottery winner in the UK, i asked him about the success, and he referred me to a very powerful voodoo doctor, (Dr Aziba), he is indeed a great man who i explain to , without no hidden details , (i really want to win the lottery so bad ) he put to work and few days latter he gave some numbers that never fails , these numbers i played and i won £3,000000,00, 3 Million pounds , (Dr Aziba) is blessed , you too can change your life too with his help, contact Email: priestazibasolutioncenter@gmail.com or whatsApp +2348100368288
DeleteThat's another amazing post to see on blogspot. Thanks for it Dear!
ReplyDeleteI have Also Read Posts Like yours Where All discussions About Real estate and Immobilien Ulm and the roles against Immobilien Einsteinstraße I Hope I t will be Very helpful to others.
good post. for Wholesale Real Estate Deals step towards RealEstateCake which is newly developed marketplace for real estate investors.
ReplyDeleteThank you so much for the sharing. All contents were expressed in a clear n simplified manner n it was meaningful too. Multifamily for Sale Columbus Ohio.
ReplyDeleteAIPL Joy Square Gurgaon Sector-63 A, Golf Course Extension Road, best commercial retail shops, food court. Call @ 9205739325 for site visit, floor plan, and payment plan etc.
ReplyDeleteThanks for sharing this. Boulos Corporation the real estate network in Florida offering you well-Constructed House for sale, Tallahassee with the finest communities and master-planned properties.
ReplyDeleteThank you for delivering this amazing post. Now get foreclosures houses deal at minimum price at RealEstateCake. It is best real estate platform in the united states.
ReplyDelete
ReplyDeleteNice, Thank you for sharing useful information to get benefit out of it.
tiger global management
Thanks for sharing such a nice post keep it up.
ReplyDeleteuniversity town
All thanks to Elegant loan firm for helping me secure a loan of $1,000,000.00 USD to establish my Foodstuff supermarket business in different places. I have been looking for financial help for the past four years. But now, I am completely stressed free with all the help of the loan officer Mr Russ Harry. So, I will advise any person who seeks funds to improve his or her business to contact this great firm for help, and it is real and tested. You can reach him through- Email --Elegantloanfirm@Hotmail.com- or Whats-app +393511617486.
ReplyDeleteSell your house fast in Allentown, NJ? We are local home buyers wanting to buy your house for cash! Call us now for a fair cash offer.
ReplyDeleteThere is a lot of option to invest Bahria town Karachi if you want to invest in the right place or at the right time so you must visit at Salaam estate & builders. I have an experience when i buy plot in bahria town karachi, they deliver best services to me.
ReplyDeleteBahria town Karachi rates
Capital Samart City Lunches
ReplyDeletesamart homes with automation abality samart City is evolution in real estate industry in Pakistan where dream come true.
Lottery is something majority of the people in the world want to win, not only winning the lottery, but they want to win big, i have been playing the lottery for couple of years now, but i haven,t really win big, personally i always think there is something behind all those winners who always win big, because my intense always tell me that every thing is possible, i manage to get in contact with one of the biggest lottery winner in the UK, i asked him about the success, and he referred me to a very powerful voodoo doctor, (Dr Aziba), he is indeed a great man who i explain to , without no hidden details , (i really want to win the lottery so bad ) he put to work and few days latter he gave some numbers that never fails , these numbers i played and i won £3,000000,00, 3 Million pounds , (Dr Aziba) is blessed , you too can change your life too with his help, contact Email: priestazibasolutioncenter@gmail.com or whatsApp +2348100368288
ReplyDeleteInformative post. Residential Alabama is the place where you can find the best deals regarding Houses Sale for Alabama at one place.
ReplyDeleteThanks for this lovely post. Get New Home Rebate Realty is giving amazing rebate back by finding home builders with them. calculate your Rebate amount Rebate Calculator
ReplyDeleteTaj residencia a way of living buy housing and plots and invest in real estate sector and secure your future.
ReplyDeleteAssuming our congress gets their act together the recovery stated previously has increased probability; if you are not, hyper-inflation you can do which can be screwed for some time to come. I'm not sure about yourself but I'm crossing my fingers and seeking best in this Real Estate in Canada.
ReplyDeleteHi Steve! Congrats on receiving such an honorable award the pride moment.
ReplyDeletemanpower recruitment agencies in Pakistan for Saudi Arabia
Informative post. Best manpower recruitmnet agency
ReplyDelete