This post is a continuation of the long version of my interview with Hites Ahir...
3. In your research, you
have found that demand patterns are consistent across countries, but supply
patterns are not. What explains this?
Housing demand is determined by, inter alia, income, prices, demographics, mortgage markets, and of
course tastes or preferences. Let’s
focus on incomes today, using Exhibit 1, taken from Malpezzi and Mayo
(1987). These are called Engel curves,
after the German economist who began the study of such budget shares in 1857.
The horizontal line represents monthly household income in dollars. The
vertical line represents the rent-to-income ratio, or budget share, at each
income level. Based on analysis of household surveys, we can trace out the average
rent-to-income ratio within each city at different levels of household income.
Negative sloping lines indicate that rents rise more slowly than incomes
(housing expenditure is income inelastic, in economist’s jargon). A flat line would indicate a constant
rent-to-income ratio for rich and poor alike; and a rising line indicates
elastic demand.
Exhibit 1
Demand for housing within a market has been found to be
“normal” which means that as incomes rise people consume more housing. No
surprise there. But while expenditure on rents rises with income, these
expenditures don’t generally rise as fast as incomes rise. Housing is inelastic
with respect to income, or in other words a necessity.
Exhibit 1 is based on a classic study Steve Mayo and I
carried out years ago in 14 cities from a range of developing countries. For clarity the dotted lines show only 4 of
the 14 city results, although the other 10 were qualitatively similar. Within markets (cities), housing consumption increases
with income, but less slowly than income.
That’s not a surprise. We see this behavior with a number of goods and
services. Food is the obvious example – because goods like food and housing are
necessities.
The solid line is different.
The 14 cities all had different average incomes, of course, and so we also
plotted the 14 rent-to-income ratios at each city’s average income. The solid line is the regression line through
these 14 points; this shows how the city curves shift up slowly as the entire
city’s income level rises. In other
words, over the very long run, as
cities develop, elasticities (responsiveness) will tend to be higher than
within a single city’s cross section, which is just a snapshot of a particular
period. Housing markets take significant
time to adjust, and single cross section snapshots do not reveal truly long run
behavior.
Owner results are qualitatively similar, although the budget
shares tend to be a little higher for owners in a given city at a given income
level.
Price elasticities (not shown on the Exhibit) are less well studied, but usually similar
in absolute value, i.e. often range from -0.4 to -0.8. As housing prices rise, the quantity of
housing consumed falls; but a bit less rapidly than the prices rise. Taking these two effects together, if
housing’s price elasticity is negative but less than one, as housing prices
rise, expenditure (price times quantity) rises, holding income and other things
equal.
One immediate consequence of this (and a plethora of other
confirmatory research) is that the common practice of adopting a single
expenditure ratio as a threshold for so-called housing affordability is very
much at odds with actual household behavior. Households around the world treat
housing as a necessity; the fraction of income devoted to it systematically
falls as incomes rise within a city.
Future demand research will not only upgrade and update
these demand estimates, but will expand our focus from developing countries
alone to a broader range of emerging markets and developing countries. How
these Engel curves behave throughout the entire range of incomes found at
different levels of development, and how they change over time, is ripe for
further study.
The bottom line about demand is not that it’s identical in all cities. Other things matter, some readily measured
like incomes, prices, and demographics; some are harder to measure including
cultural effects on preferences. Nevertheless housing demand appears to be remarkably
systematic and predictable, given a few key variables. Supply is more complicated.
Exhibit 2, from a review I’ve just begun with Lingxiao Li,
presents stylized supply curves for housing generated from the elasticities
estimated by 6 studies of 15 different countries. There are many caveats about the strict comparability
of these different studies, so think of Exhibit 2 as suggestive, not precise.
Housing supply elasticities (responsiveness) appear to be all over the
map. In cities like Bangkok and Atlanta,
during the periods studied, small increases in housing prices begin to quickly
call forth new supply. That supply can be from new construction; but also from
upgrading and modification of the existing stock, through what is often called
“filtering.” With these sources of supply working well, supply curves in these
markets are flat.
At the other extreme, cities like Seoul and San Francisco
have low estimated price elasticities of supply. In these cities real estate developers and
managers of existing real estate assets are constrained in some fashion, and
slow to respond to initial price signals. Thus their supply curves are
relatively steep.
The estimations behind Exhibit 2 vary in their econometric
technique and type and duration of data, so, as already noted, precise
numerical comparisons should be taken with grains of salt. But qualitatively, nobody
familiar with those cities would be surprised that Atlanta’s real estate supply
is much more responsive than San Francisco’s; or that Bangkok’s is more
responsive than Seoul’s. Especially in the 1980s when the first studies of
these elasticities were completed.
In fact, Bangkok’s real estate supply system was later
disrupted by the excesses of the hot money-driven real estate bubble that was
the trigger for the 1997 Asian Financial Crisis (see Mera and Renaud). Seoul’s supply system, while still problematic in some
respects, is somewhat more responsive since 1990s era reforms (see Kim and
Park). So there’s probably been some convergence in these supply elasticities
although we’d certainly benefit from some careful research on this question. A
lot of research remains to be done on the supply side, including understanding
the time varying nature of changing responsiveness. Mayo and Shepard provide a
template for research on this question, and some evidence from Malaysia.
On the other hand many observers argue that the difference
between supply conditions in U.S. metropolitan areas has increased over time (Ganong
and Shoag). Certainly the volatility in
U.S. housing prices has increased, and also the correlations across markets has
also increased, making it increasingly difficult to diversify across regional
housing markets (Malpezzi forthcoming).
Malpezzi and Wachter make another salient point about
supply. As Samuelson’s famous paper on the Le Chatelier principle reminds us
that as we take longer and longer run perspectives, elasticities necessarily
increase in absolute value. The central insight is a simple one: the longer the
time period under consideration, the more ability we have to adjust either
demand or supply or both. As Malpezzi and Wachter showed with simple
simulations, and Wheaton demonstrated with a more sophisticated model some
years earlier, this implies that markets with an initially more inelastic
market much more readily generate large boom and bust cycles. In elastic
markets, like Atlanta, and Bangkok, booms are harder (though not impossible) to
start. As I have told my students for years, every real estate boom ends with
something else that starts with the letter B.
References
Chai, Andreas, and Alessio Moneta. "Retrospectives: Engel Curves." Journal of Economic Perspectives 24, no. 1 (2010): 225-240.
Ganong, Peter, and Daniel Shoag. "Why Has Regional Income Convergence in the Us Declined?", (2013).
Kim, Kyung Hwan, Sock-Yong Phang, and Susan Wachter. "Supply Elasticity of Housing." 66-74: International Encyclopaedia of Housing and Home, 2012.
Kim, Kyung-Hwan, and Miseon Park. "Housing Policies in the Republic of Korea." THE HOUSING CHALLENGE IN EMERGING ASIA, (2016): 92.
Malpezzi, Stephen. "Economic Analysis of Housing Markets in Developing and Transition Economies." In Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics. Volume 3. Applied Urban Economics, edited by Paul Cheshire and Edwin S. Mills, 1791-1864. New York and Oxford: Elsevier Science North-Holland, 1999.
________. "Residential Real Estate in the U.S. Financial Crisis, the Great Recession, and Their Aftermath." Taiwan Economic Review, (Forthcoming).
Malpezzi, Stephen, and Stephen K. Mayo. "The Demand for Housing in Developing Countries: Empirical Estimates from Household Data." Economic Development and Cultural Change 35, no. 4 (1987): 687-721.
Malpezzi, Stephen, Stephen K Mayo, and David J) (with Gross. Housing Demand in Developing Countries. Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 1985.
Malpezzi, Stephen, and Susan M. Wachter. "The Role of Speculation in Real Estate Cycles." Journal of Real Estate Literature 13, no. 2 (2005): 143-64.
Mayo, Stephen, and Stephen Sheppard. "Housing Supply and the Effects of Stochastic Development Control." Journal of Housing Economics 10, no. 2 (2001): 109-128.
Mera, Koichi, and Bertrand Renaud. Asia's Financial Crisis and the Role of Real Estate: ME Sharpe Inc, 2000.
Samuelson, Paul A. "The Le Chatelier Principle in Linear Programming." Rand Corporation, memorandum, 1949.
Wheaton, William C. "Real Estate" Cycles": Some Fundamentals." Real Estate Economics 27, no. 2 (1999): 209-211.
Next Post: Progress and Challenges in Developing Country Housing Markets
Next Post: Progress and Challenges in Developing Country Housing Markets
No comments:
Post a Comment